essay代写,代写assignment,paper代写,代写留学作业,英国作业

导航切换

QQ:
153688106

二维码

加拿大代写留学生作业|Synergy Motive

浏览: 日期:2020-06-10

Synergy Motive

Chapter 2: Literature Review

2.1 Motives for Mergers and Acquisitions

Several academicians and researched have written literature on the three major motives for takeovers: the synergy motive, the agency motive and the hubris motive. Berkovitch and Narayanan (1993) define the synergy motive as a takeover that takes place because of economic gains that result by merging the resources of the two firms. Managers of targets and acquirers will agree to a takeover if it the potential combination is forecasted to bring profits to both sets of shareholders, that is, the main motive for the takeover is to maximize shareholder value. There are several reasons for a synergistic takeover- an exogenous change in supply and/or demand, technological innovations, or purposeful investments by the bidding firm. The value created by the combination may result from more efficient management, economies of scale, improved production techniques, the combination of complementary resources, the redeployment of assets to more profitable uses, the exploitation of market power (Bradley et al, 1987).

Martynova and Renneboog (2006) explain two kinds of synergies - operating synergy and financial synergy. If the synergy reflects economies of scale , vertical integration, the transfer of knowledge or skills by the bidder's management team, and a reduction in agency costs by bringing organization-specific assets under common ownership and the elimination of duplicate activities then they are called operating synergies (Ravenscraft and Scherer 1987, 1989). Moreover, operating synergies are seen more often than not in mergers and acquisitions between related industries (Comment and Jarrell 1995). Financial synergies may include improved cash flow stability, lower probability of bankruptcy (Lewellen 1971, Higgins and Schall 1975), access to cheaper funds, the existence of an internal capital market (Bhide 1990), the possibility to use underutilized tax shields, as well as contracting efficiencies created by a reduction in managers' employment risk (Amihud and Lev 1981) (Martynova and Renneboog, 2006). Financial synergies are seen more often in diversifying takeovers (Martynova and Renneboog, 2006).

A second motive for mergers or acquisition is the agency motive. This takes place when the acquirer's managers engage in a takeover for the management's self-interest. They may prefer to maximize corporate growth rather than corporate value as their private benefits tend to increase in line with firm size as pointed out by Goergen and Rennerboog (2004). Diversification of the managements personal portfolio (Amihud and Lev (1981)), use of free cash flow to increase the size of the firm (Jenson (1986)) and acquiring assets that increase the firms dependence on the management(Shliefer and Vishny (1989) are few other reasons for agency motive (Berkovitch and Narayan, 1993)) This motive enables managers to extract wealth from the shareholders. Therefore, in such takeovers, the correlations between the target's value and the bidder's value and between the target's value and the total value will be negative as targets shareholders, realizing their value to the acquirers management, will attempt to obtain some value arising out of the takeover creating what is known as they agency problem. Higher the agency problems lower the acquirer gains.

The Hubris motive maintains that acquisitions take place due to manager's mistakes in evaluating potential targets and not due to any synergy gains (Roll,1986). If there is an equal opportunity that managers are likely to overestimate as underestimate the synergy, they will engage in the takeover only when it is overestimated and hence end up paying too much for the target. As a result, higher the target gain, lower the bidder gain, such total gain is zero with wealth being transferred from the bidder to the target (Berkovitch and Narayanan, 1993).

However, the existing empirical evidence on the above three motives are unable to distinguish between the motives. Bradley, Desai and Kim (1998) argue that takeovers are value increasing transactions because total gains are positive in their sample of takeovers. Interestingly, the gains for the acquiring shareholders are negative in more than half the cases implying that hubris or agency motives may be the dominant factor. In the same nerve, Malatesta (1983) illustrates that mergers are value increasing transactions for targets but the opposite for acquirers concluding that the agency motive might be the driving factor. Firth (1980), using a sample of U.K takeovers finds evidence proving that the hubris hypothesis is consistent. Goergen and Renneboog (2004) find significantly positive correlation between target shareholder gains and total gains as well as target and bidder gains suggesting that synergies are the main motive for takeovers (only in the case for bids with total positive wealth).

2.2 Value drivers of bidder and target abnormal returns

Considerable amount of empirical research has been done on mergers and acquisitions in the past with a unanimous conclusion that takeovers create value for the combined firm, with the majority of the gains accruing to the target shareholders. Target shareholders in nearly all cases receive large premiums (on average 10% to 30%) relative to the pre-announcement share price (Martynova and Renneboog 2006) Similar to the domestic acquisitions, target shareholders in cross border M&A activity are seen earning positive abnormal returns (see Harris and Ravenscraft, 1991; Cebeynoyan et al, 1992; Cheng and Chan, 1995), although Danbolt (2002) finds no statistical difference between short-run abnormal returns for UK targets of domestic mergers and acquisitions (18.46%) and those of cross-border takeovers (19.68%).

A comparison of the shareholder's wealth between US and UK reveal the following results. Conn and Connell (1990) and Feils (1993) conclude that wealth effect for the US firms is significantly larger than UK firms (40% versus 18% in Conn and Connell and 26% versus 16% in Feils). Jarrell and Poulsen (1989), Servaes (1991), Kaplan and Weisbach (1992), Mulherin and Boone (2000), for instance, report average US target abnormal returns of 29% (for 1963-86), 24% (for 1972-87), 27% for (1971-82), and 21% (for 1990-99), respectively(Martynova and Renneboog, 2006). Similarly to their US counterparts, UK and Continental European targets gain average announcement returns of 24% during the period 1955-85 (Franks and Harris 1989), 19% in 1966-91 (Danbolt 2004), and 13% in 1990-2001 (Goergen and Renneboog 2004).

Empirical evidence from previous literature suggests there is a considerable contrast between the large share price returns of target firms and the frequently negligible returns of bidding firms. Jenson and Ruback( 1983) and Frank, Broyles and Hecht in their research on US firms showed that targets clearly gain and bidders gain, or at least do not lose.(Franks and Harris (1989). For the bidding firms, there is mixed findings in the literature about the sign of the price reaction to the announcement of an M&A. While some report small negative announcement returns for the acquirers (see e.g. Andrade et al. 2001, Mulherin and Boone 2000, Franks et al. 1991, Healy et al. 1992), others finds zero or small positive announcement abnormal returns (see e.g. Moeller and Schlingemann 2005, Schwert 2000, Loderer and Martin 1990, Asquith et al. 1983) (Martynova and Renneboog, 2006). But, bidder shareholders realize abnormal returns immediately around the announcement day which are insignificantly different from zero, regardless of the sign.

Similarly, Goergen and Renneboog (2004) conclude from the existing comprehensive literature that mergers and acquisitions are value creating for shareholders as target shareholders earn large positive abnormal returns and the bidder shareholders do not lose on average. Likewise, Halpern (1973), Mandelker (1974) Asquith (1983) Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988) prove that successful acquisitions create value for shareholders, but Malatesta (1983) and Roll(1986) refute this. While some studies conclude that gains from a takeover go to the target (Dodd (1980) Mandelker (1974), Asquith (1983) Halpern (1973)), some others find that gains are spilt between the acquirer and the target ( Franks, Broyles and Hecht (1977) in contrast report gains to both parties and yet other prove that bidding firms shareholder earning positive and significantly gains from successful takeovers (Asquith (1983), Bruner and Mullins(1983), Dodd and Ruback (1977)) (Frank and Harris, 1989).

Significant amount of research has been done to under the reasons for such changes in the target and bidder shareholders returns. A number of value drivers for target and bidder shareholder returns have been exposed by these studies. In the following section, we present the existing finding on a few of these value drivers.

2.2.1 Form of Bid - Hostile versus Friendly bids

An acquisition is defined as hostile, if the management of the potential target, for any reason, rejects the offer for takeover. Among other reasons, hostility maybe due to extract a higher premium from the acquirers for the target shareholders (Schwert, 2000) or the target management may believe that the proposal does not match their firm's strategy (Goergen and Renneboog, 2006). Moreover, according to the shareholder-welfare hypothesis as noted by Huang and Walking (1987), when there is resistance to a bid, it may result in the shareholders interest in the form of higher premiums from the current bidder or another one. Consistent with the shareholder-welfare hypothesis, Kummer and Hoffmeister (1978) account for higher abnormal returns during the initial announcement month for hostile tender offers.

Hostile bids generate a higher abnormal return for the target (12.6% on day 0 and almost 30% with the price run-up) on the announcement day whereas the bidders shareholders earn -2.5% showing their disapproval for the takeover as shown in the research of Georgen and Renneboog (2004). Alternatively, if the bid is a friendly one, or is a merger then they show that the acquisition generates a positive return of 2.5%. The reason for such bidder reaction, they say is, because when hostile bids are made, the share price of the target automatically reflects the expectations of such opposition which leads to an upward revision of the offer prices and hence the takeover premium to be paid. Moreover, the bidder will usually incur additional costs, including litigation and delay, and may be forced to pay higher premiums to target shareholders to encourage tendering (Jarrel and Poulsen, 1986). On the other hand, Gregory (1997); Loughran and Vijh (1997); and Lang et al (1989) show that hostile bids generate higher target as well as bidder returns than the announcement of friendly mergers or acquisitions. From the merged firm perspective, Kuipers at al (2003) show that for offers opposed by target firm's management, value is created for the combined firm but target shareholders earn lower returns (albeit not at significant levels).

Excessive managerial resistance, on the other hand, might only hinder the success of the deal as pointed out by Huang and Walking (1987). Similarly, Jensen and Ruback (1983) show that since an opposed bid increases acquisition costs for bidding firms they may forego the acquisition attempt that otherwise (if the bid were friendly, or less resistant) would have been profitable. Abandonment of these attempts produces what Jensen and Ruback term thetruncation phenomenon.

If a target firms shareholder reject a bid, in favor of the current management, then the shareholders the unsuccessful bidding firm will not experience any abnormal price changes. However, if the same target firm accepts the offer of another rival bidder, then the primary bidding firm will experience significant wealth loss around the days where the tender offer is made by the successful rival bidder (Bradley et al, 1982).

Looking at hostile bids from a corporate governance point of view, Rossi and Volpin (2004) show that hostile deals are more likely to take place in countries with better shareholder protection because good protection of minority shareholders makes control more contestable by reducing the private benefits of control.

2.2.2 Method of Payment- Cash versus Stock

A number of empirical studies investigate the rationale for offering cash for some acquisitions and stock for other acquisitions. Cumulative abnormal returns, of the bidders and targets, tend to differ most significantly and noticeably with the form of payment. Huang and Walking (1987), Travlos (1987), Servaes (1991) and Andrade et al (2001) find that cash offers generally induce significantly higher abnormal returns than do stock offers, for both the target and the bidding firm shareholders, in other words, the method of payment influences the takeover premium that must be paid.

Strong evidence is found by Goergen and Renneboog (2004) showing targets are highly sensitive to the means of payment used. They show that cash offers induce the CAR to increase by 10% compared to equity offers which shows an increase of only 6.7% in the CAR. In conclusion, they show that no matter whatever the event window, the CAAR of cash financed bids at significantly higher than other bids.

Conversely, Goergen and Renneboog (2004) show a completely different picture for the acquiring firms CAR. Regardless of the size of the event window, the bidding firm's shareholders react more favorably to stock offers (1%) than cash offers (0.4%). This result is in contradiction to that of Travlos( 1987) who shows that for pure stock offers, the bidder shareholders experience significant losses while in cash offers the bidding firms shareholders earn normal rates of return. Amongst others, such mixed empirical findings have been reported by Huang and Walking (1987), Franks and Harris (1989), Harris and Ravenscroft (1991), Eckbo et al (1990) and Loughran and Vijh (1997).

Such reaction in favor of cash offers to equity offers can be interpreted as a signal of the bidder's confidence in its abilities to exploit the synergies from the potential takeover without sharing the future value creation with the target shareholders (Goergen and Renneboog, 2004). Moreover, Amihud, Lev, and Travlos (1990), build on Harris and Raviv (1988) and Stulz (1988) and find that managers who value control prefer to pay cash for acquisitions to avoid ownership dilution and the possible loss of control (Ghosh and Ruland, 1998).

Amongst others, there are several factors that influence the choice of payment. Firstly, when targets are compensated in cash during an acquisition, the transaction becomes taxable, and the bidders end up paying a higher premium to the target. On the other hand, if they are compensated in stock (or any other form of payment), the taxation liability can be deferred or be paid immediately, depending on the situation, and the bidders do not have to pay a higher premium (Huang and Walking, 1987). Hence, due to these differential tax treatments cash offers have a higher return than stock offers, that is, targets demand a higher premium in situations that will force them to pay immediate taxes on their capital gains. (Wansley, Lane, and Yang [42]) (Travlos, 1987)

Furthermore, agency effects (as stated by Jenson (1986)) can also be a motive for acquirers to use cash instead of stock as a takeover currency. Firms will prefer using the excess cash flow to fund other activities, like takeovers, rather than returning this amount to the shareholders. Therefore, firms who are influenced by the agency effects will use cash to finance a takeover compared to other methods.

Regulation effect is another factor influencing the choice of payment. Wansley, Lane and Yang (1983) note that for stock offers, the acquirer must take a prior approval from the Securities and Exchange Commission before the targets begin to tender their shares. Huang and Walking (1987) argue that this could become a problem in hostile bids as the processing time for the approval is long, giving leeway to the target management to leak information to preferred acquirers or it could induce other bidders to join the race. In contrast, if bidders use cash instead of stock, they can start acquiring the target within a few weeks and avoid unnecessary payments of high premiums due to competing bids. Thus, if cash is used, then prior approval of the SEC is unwanted and acquisition becomes faster, making it a preferred form of payment in cases of hostile takeover where time is crucial and the speed of transactions matter.

In perfectly markets with symmetrically informed agents, the method of payment to finance acquisitions is economically irrelevant. However, if managers of an acquiring firm are aware that their shares are worth more than the current market price, that is, they are overpriced; then they will prefer to finance the takeover with cash. Conversely, if they feel that their shares are below the market price (underpriced), then they will want to use stocks as a takeover currency. Such behavior of managers arises due to information asymmetries (Myers and Mjluf, 1934), another factor that influences the method of payment. When the bidding firm, uses equity to finance the bid, the market will perceive this as negative news regarding the bidder's true stock value (signaling hypothesis). This negative reaction of the market participants on the announcement day is reflected in the negative returns for the bidder shareholders. Hence, such information asymmetries between the managers of a firm and the external investors may have a bearing on the choice of payment to be used.

Goergen and Renneboog (2004) show that in their sample of takeover, the smaller ones are all cash bids, while the larger ones involve equity. This implies that for large bids, the choice of payment is either all equity or a mixed offer as it becomes difficult to raise such large amounts of cash. As a result, the choice of means of payment does not act as a signal to the market about the over/undervaluation of the bidder's equity.

In conclusion, it becomes necessary to control the method of payment as most cross border deals are cash offers (Starks and Wei, 2003; Rossi and Volpin, 2004) and we need to control the likelihood that higher abnormal returns earned by the target and the bidder are driven by the fact that most of these acquisition are cash offers.

2.2.3 Relative Size

From the targets size perspective, an increasing its size relative to that of the acquirer would create an impact which would be readily observable in the acquirers return. In this context, if the acquisition is a wealth increasing one, then the largest positive return will be reflected when the target is relatively large compared to the bidding firm. Asquith, Bruner and Mullins (1983) and Travlos (1987) conducted their tests on the relationship between relative size and the returns to the acquirers, they found a significantly positive relation between the two (Jarrell and Poulson, 1989). However, Goergen and Renneboog (2008) argue in their research that the size of the target relative to the size of the bidder does not have an impact on target and bidder wealth effects. But they also highlight that a probable reason for such a conclusion could be that their study focused on large M&A deals and that therefore the average relative size was fairly homogeneous. Jarrell and Poulsen (1989) conclude that as the target size, relative to the bidder increases, the bidder firm shareholders experience a significant appreciation in their share prices. They measured the relative size as the value of outstanding equity of target divided by the value of outstanding equity of the bidder at three months before the transaction.

Ghosh and Ruland (1998) have investigated the correlation between managerial incentive for control rights in the combined firm and the relative size. Their results illustrate that if the target firm is small compared to the acquirer, then the target firm's managers' influence in the combined firm will also be small. Furthermore, they examine the relation between the method of acquisition and the relative size of the target and conclude that for acquiring firm managers who are concerned about the potential dilution of equity or the loss of control while acquiring a target larger in size compared to them, will prefer to offer cash instead of equity as compensation.

While calculating the effects of mergers on bidders, the large size of the bidder compared to the target can pose potential problems as presented by Frank and Harris (1989). They argue that this difference in sizes can make the gains or losses from the acquisition ambiguous. Conversely, if the target is bigger than the bidder, the bidder does not significantly lose. Controlling the size of the bidder, helps us detect the impact of the acquisition on the bidders share price (Frank and Harris, 1989).

2.2.4 Industry Relatedness of the Bidding and Target firms - Focus versus Diversification Strategy

Diversifying a business has several advantages- greater operating efficiency, less incentive to forego positive net present value projects, greater debt capacity, and lower taxes. Contrarily, there as costs associated with such diversification like the unrestricted resources to undertake value-decreasing investments, cross-subsidies that allow poor segments to drain resources from better-performing segments, and misalignment of incentives between central and divisional managers. There is no clear prediction about the overall value effect of diversification.

Berger and Ofek (1994) in their study of the effects of diversification on firm value are of the view that diversification reduces value. They estimate the value of each segment as if it were operating as a separate firm and concluded that the average value lost was 13% to 15% over the sample period. This loss is reduced when the diversification. Comment and Jarrell (1994) find a negative relation between abnormal stock returns and diversification. Similarly, Lang and Stulz (1994) also find a negative relation between shareholder wealth and diversification.

Doukas et al (2001) examined the effects of corporate diversification on the short term and long term wealth effects of 101 Swedish bidding firms. The results were the same as above- diversification does not create value. Furthermore, they provide evidence that unrelated diversification result in greater agency cost and operating inefficiencies which have a negative effect on the short and long term performance of the firm. This implies that unrelated diversification is a burden on shareholder wealth. On the contrary, they emphasize that if firms engage in expansion of their primary line of business (related diversification), then announcement and post-acquisition performance gains are realized (Doukas et al, 2001). In the same vein, Harris and Ravenscraft (1991) present that relation diversification not only increase the efficiency of the firm but also have a positive effect on economies of scale and market power. Martynova and Renneboog (2006) find that when bidding firms engage in related diversification, bidding shareholders earn significantly while target shareholders earn more in unrelated diverfication. The reason for such opposite effects on wealth is bidders tend to overpay due to aggressive bidding, implying that acquisitions are driven by motives other than shareholder profit.

2.2.5 Contested nature of the bids - Single versus Multiple bids

Empirical analysis by several researchers (Bradly, Kim and Desai, 1988; Kuipers, 2003) show evidence that the greater the bidding competition for assets, higher the returns to targets and lower the returns to acquirers. Franks and Harris show that target abnormal returns are one third or two thirds higher when there are multiple bids. These results are in line with those of Bradly, Desai and Kim (1988) who state that multiple bidders increase abnormal returns by over 40% to target shareholders, compared with less than 30% in the single bidder case.

However, Frank and Harris (1987) do reason that in challenged bids, the total synergistic gains are larger. Hence, target shareholders not only benefit at the expense of bidding firm shareholders, but also from the synergistic gains of the deal. This is acknowledged by Jarrel and Poulsen (---) who are of the opinion that if an acquisition is not challenged, then the target will have to accept the number of shares offered by the bidders, but in the opposite case due to competition, the target will benefit from the merger gains as the offer price will be driven up and larger share of the returns will go to the target compared to the bidder. Franks and Harris (1987) also conducted a direct comparison research on contested bids between two countries. Their evidence suggests contested bids lead to higher target wealth in both countries.

Virtually all researchers have found that target wealth increases in contested bids, but in terms of bidder's wealth, there is a mixed finding. While Bradley, Kim and Desai (1988) show that takeover wealth to acquiring firm shareholders are significantly positive in single-bidder contests and insignificantly different from zero in multiple-bidder's case, Franks and Harris (1987) find no such substantial result. Franks and Harris explain that the competition amongst bidders reduces the average gains for the acquirers, the negative effect being especially severe for late-bidder acquirers, commonly known as white knights.

Furthermore, both Jarrell and Bradley, hypothesize that post Williams Act, the acquirer's returns should have decreased further as now the competing bidders could use the information produced by the original bidders, and the target returns should have increased. They prove their hypothesis as they found that abnormal returns to bidders declined from an average of about 9% prior to the Williams Act to about 6% following the adoption of the Williams Act, and that returns to targets increased by about 20% (Jarrell and Poulsen, ---)

2.3 Impact of differences in corporate governance regulations on bidders and target performance and value in cross-border takeovers

Corporate control is defined as the rights to determine the management of corporate resources - that is, the rights to hire, fire and set the compensation of top-level managers [Fama and Jensen (1983a, b)]. It encompasses activities that range from controlling the use of corporate resources, such as legal and regulatory systems and competition in product and input market, to controlling the majority seats of a firm's board of management. When a bidding firm acquires a target firm, the managing and controlling activities of the target firm are transferred to the board of directors of the acquiring firm. Therefore, through acquisitions the top management of the acquiring firm acquires the rights to manage the resources of the target firm.

Contractual devices, like cross border mergers and acquisitions, (re) incorporations, and cross listings, are means enabling firms to change its national corporate governance standards and adopt a new one (Goergen and Renneboog, 2004). According to Rossi and Volpin (2004) selling to a foreign firm is a form of contractual convergence similar to the decision of listing in countries with better corporate governance and better-developed capital markets. Pagano, et al. (2002) and Reese and Weisbach (2002) highlight that firm's from countries with weak legal protection for minority shareholders list abroad more frequently than do firms from other countries.

Nevertheless, the possibility of a world wide convergence in corporate governance standards is a subject of debate amongst various academicians. While Hansmann and Kraakman (2001) suggest that a formal convergence towards the acquirers governance standards will happen soon, Coffee (1999) argues that diffences in corporate governance will persist but with some degree of functional convergence (Rossi and Volpin, 2004).

Rossi and Volpin (2004) focus on merger activities and the target premium aggregated by countries. They hypothesize that cost of capital is reduced when the acquirer hails from a superior system of corporate governance than the target, making the acquisition of the target a sensible choice. On the same lines, Coffee (1999) concludes that firms from better investor protection system will acquire firms from lower protection systems. Furthermore, when most targets are from countries with weaker shareholder protection and disclosure practices they stand to gain from lower cost of capital associated with high investor protection. Rossi and Volpin (2004) base their findings on those of La Porta et al (2000), showing that a more active market for mergers and acquisitions is the outcome of a stronger corporate governance regime. They conclude that cross border M&A's enhance convergence towards stronger investor protection, which has a positive impact on the volume of takeovers, bid premiums and the number of hostile takeovers. In addition, better protection in the bidder country, allows the bidder to make all equity offers.

Recent studies have been carried out to assess the impact of the legal and corporate governance environment on the valuation of a firm. These studies have been done at both the firm specific and industry level. Bris and Cabolis (2005) and Kuipers et al (2003) are amongst a few who have focused their research on firm specific environment.

Kuipers et al, (2003) test the impact of the legal environment on the shareholders returns of US targets, foreign acquirers and the combined firm. They further test the agency cost contracting hypothesis of the acquiring firm as captured by the legal environment and quality of protection provided to the security holders based on the LLSV indices. Agency cost contracting hypothesis states that firms from strong investor protection countries will act in the interests of their shareholders (or creditors, if creditor protection is superior compared to the shareholders) and will accordingly engage in value increasing (or value decreasing) investments. Alternatively, there is the contractual convergence hypothesis which states that firms from weak investor protection countries acquire firms from high investor protection, with the aim of bootstrapping themselves to a better system of governance. In support of Wurgler (2000) and LLSV(2002) Kuipers et al.(2003) conclude that- The existence of a strong rule of law and security owner protection mechanisms acts as a substitute contracting mechanism for mitigating the classic agency cost of the firm (Kuiper et al, 2003). With regards to shareholder returns, they find that shareholders of the acquiring firm stand to gain when their rights are protected and the combined firm is more valuable but if the creditor rights are stronger then they earn lower returns (keeping in mind that Kuipers et al, focused on US targets alone).

Starks and Wei (2003) use country-level corporate governance focusing on the U.S target returns and argue that target shareholders should be compensated for adopting inferior corporate governance standards. In other words, they argue that takeover premium should decrease with an increase in the level of acquirer's home country corporate governance. Moreover, they elucidate that the importance of the bidder's corporate governance is of significance only in stock offers, as only when the form of compensation is stock, the target is exposed to increased risk from low corporate governance standards. In a cash for-stock merger, the shareholders of the newly created firm are the old shareholders of the acquirer and thus unaffected, while in a stock-for-stock merger, some shareholders of the newly created firm are located in the country of nationality of the target. In conclusion, they prove that the difference in corporate governance regimes across countries have a significant impact on the cross-border merger premiums, suggesting that corporate governance has a valuation effect.

Bris and Cabolis (2008) find that takeover premiums in cross-border deals are increasing in the level of shareholder protection and the quality of accounting standards in the acquirer's country and that the pattern holds only when target nationality changes completely and this takes place only in 100% acquisitions. This is contradiction to the finding of Starks and Wei (2003) who find a negative relationship between takeover premium and the acquirer's corporate governance standards. Furthermore, they do not find a symmetric effect, that is, if the bidder has a worse protection regime which is enforced on the target or if the merged firm chooses accounting standards that are worse than before the merger, the takeover premium is not significantly lower.

Wang and Xie (2007) report positive and significant impact of positive spillover effects of shareholder rights on both the target and acquiring shareholders wealth in domestic U.S mergers and acquisitions. They also examine the operating performance of the combined firm and conclude that difference in the shareholder rights index has a positively significant impact. On the same lines, Martynova and Renneboog (2008) have studied the valuation effects of corporate governance spillover in cross-border M & A's. They hypothesize that the variation in the different corporate governance standards will be accentuated in cross-border transaction compared to domestic deals. When the bidder is subject to better corporate governance standards than the target, the acquisition may result in the target importing the better corporate governance standards from the bidder. This improved governance is expected to generate additional value which should be reflected in the abnormal share prices of both the target and the bidder. This effect, in the case for full takeovers, has been termed as positive spillover by law. If the takeover is a partial one, then the same effect is termed as spillover by control. On the other hand, if the target firm is from a country with high investor protection standards and it is being acquired by a country with low investor protection standards, then this can have two effects. The target firm could either adopt the poor standards of the acquirer thereby suffering from low abnormal returns and a loss of in value of target assets (negative spillover by law) or the acquirer could voluntarily adopt the superior governance standards of the target and enjoy the benefits of a higher investor protection regime (bootstrapping). The effects of bootstrapping, as explained by Martynova and Renneboog (2008) and Starks and Wei (2003) could be amplified in cases of partial takeovers, all stock offers and mixed offer as the target shareholder will remain involved in the merged company and may actively resist managerial decisions. In their research, Martynova and Renneboog (2008) show their positive spillover by law hypothesis was supported while the negative spillover by law hypothesis was not. Moreover, the bootstrapping hypothesis was proved only for partial takeovers.

2.4 Summary of the literature review

In the first section we identified the different motives for merger and acquisitions. Empirical research points out three main motives - synergy, agency and hubris. As explained, the synergy motive creates vale for both, the target and the acquirer shareholders, while agency and hubris motives reduce value. We then proceeded to explain the different drivers of value in mergers and acquisitions - form of bid, the method of payment, relative size of the bidder, effects of diversification and contested nature of the bid. Different views of different academicians and researchers were presented in this section. Finally, we presented in brief, the works of various papers that have studied the effects of corporate governance on bidder and target shareholders wealth, specifically that of Rossi and Volpin (2004), Kuipers et al (2003), Starks and Wei (2003), Bris and Cabolis (2005), Wang and Xie (2007) and Martynova and Renneboog (2008).

 

协同效应动机
第2章:文献综述
2.1兼并与收购的动机
多名院士和研究的书面文学的三大动机的收购的协同动机,的代理动机和傲慢的动机。 Berkovitch和纳拉亚南(1993)定义的协同动机作为收购发生,因为经济收益,通过合并两家公司的资源的结果。如果它的潜在的组合预计将带来利润双方股东,也就是说,收购的主要动机是实现股东价值最大化的目标和收购方的经理会同意接管。有几个原因收购的协同供应和/或需求的外生变化,技术创新,由招标公司或有意投资。创造的价值的结合,可能会导致从更高效的管理,规模经济,改进生产技术,资源互补的组合,资产调配至更有利可图的用途,市场力量的剥削(布拉德利等人,1987)。
马尔季诺娃Renneboog的(2006)解释二种协同作用 - 经营协同效应和财务协同效应。如果协同效应反映规模经济,垂直整合,由投标人的管理团队的知识或技能的转移,以及通过将组织特定资产共同拥有一个减少代理成本,并消除重复的活动,然后他们被称为经营协同效应(Ravenscraft和舍雷尔1987年,1989年)。此外,经营协同效应往往不是看到相关行业(注释和1995年贾雷尔)之间的兼并和收购。财务协同效应可能包括提高现金流的稳定性,降低破产概率(卢埃林希金斯和1971年,1975年汤若望),获得更便宜的资金,内部资本市场的存在拜德(1990),使用未充分利用的税盾的可能性,以及作为承包经理的就业风险(Amihud和1981年列弗)(2006年)马尔季诺娃Renneboog的减少创建的效率。财务协同效应更经常看到在多元化收购(马尔季诺娃Renneboog的,2006年)。
兼并或收购的第二个动机是该机构的动机。这发生时,收购方的经理接管从事管理自身的利益。他们可能更喜欢企业的成长,而不是企业价值最大化作为自己的私人利益往往由格尔根Rennerboog的(2004)指出,在符合企业规模增加。多元化的管理个人投资组合(Amihud和列弗(1981)),使用免费的现金流,以增加企业规模(简森(1986))及收购资产的管理,从而增加了企业的依赖性(Shliefer和Vishny(1989 )代理动机是其他一些原因(Berkovitch和纳拉扬,1993)),此动机,使管理人员能够提取从股东财富。因此,在这样的收购,之间目标的价值和投标人的价值和目标的价值和总价值之间的相关性将是负目标股东,收购方管理实现自己的价值,会试图获取所引申出来的一些值收购创建了被称为他们的代理问题。更高的代理问题,降低收购方的收益。
傲慢的动机保持收购由于经理在评估潜在的目标,而不是由于任何协同收益(卷,1986年)的失误。如果有一个平等的机会,管理者很可能高估低估的协同作用,他们将从事收购,只有当它被高估,从而最终付出太多的目标。因此,较高的目标收益,降低投标人的收益,这样的总收益为零,从投标人的财富被转移的的目标(Berkovitch和纳拉亚南,1993)。
然而,现有的实证证据对上述三种动机是无法区分的动机。布拉德利,德赛和Kim(1​​998)认为,收购总收益值增加交易,因为在他们的样本的收购是积极。有趣的是,获得股东的收益为负一半以上的情况下,这意味着傲慢或机构的动机可能是主导因素。马拉泰斯塔(1983)说明在相同的神经,兼并值增加交易的目标,但收购方得出结论认为,该机构的动机可能是驱动因素相反。弗斯(1980),使用英国收购的样本,发现证据证明傲慢假说是一致的。 (2004格尔根Renneboog的)发现目标股东收益和总收益显着正相关关系,表明协同效应是收购的主要动机(只为与总阳性财富投标的情况下)的目标和中标收益。
2.2投标人的价值驱动因素和目标异常报酬
大量的实证研究已经做了在过去的兼并和收购,收购合并后的公司创造价值,与广大的收益目标股东一致的结论。目标公司股东在几乎所有情况下收到大量保费(平均10%至30%)相对的前,公告份额价格(2006年马尔季诺娃Renneboog)与国内收购,目标公司股东在跨边界中号&A活动都看到收入正异常回报(见哈里斯和Ravenscraft,1991; Cebeynoyan等,1992;郑和陈,1995年),,虽然Danbolt(2002)发现短期异常收益为英国国内兼并和收购的目标(18.46%),差异无统计学意义的跨境收购(19.68%)。
股东的财富在美国和英国之间的比较,揭示了以下的结果。康恩和康奈尔(1990)和Feils(1993)的结论,为美国公司的财富效应是明显大于英国企业与康恩和康奈尔和18%,26%和16%Feils(40%)。 Servaes的贾雷尔和波尔森(1989),(1991),卡普兰和Weisbach(1992),马尔赫林和布恩(2000),例如,美国平均目标报告异常报酬为29%(1963年至1986年),24%(1972年为-87),27%(1971年至1982年),21%(1990-99),(马尔季诺娃Renneboog的,2006年)。同样,他们的美国同行,英国和欧洲大陆的目标,获得平均24%的回报,1955年至1985年期间(1989年弗兰克斯和哈里斯)公告,19%在1966年至1991年(2004年Danbolt),1990至2001年的13%(格尔根和Renneboog 2004)。
从以前的文献中的实证证据表明大股价回报的目标公司,经常可以忽略不计回报的投标公司之间存在着相当大的反差。简森和低价注入上市公司等等,而通过重组本地(1983)和弗兰克的Broyles和赫克特的美国公司在他们的研究表明,目标明确和投标人获得收益,或至少不输。(弗兰克斯和哈里斯(1989)。对于投标公司,有混合文学之公布,对价格反应的标志结果的M&A虽然一些报告小负公告回报为收购方(见如安德拉德等2001,马尔赫林和布恩2000年,弗兰克斯等。1991,Healy等人,1992年),别人发现异常为零或小的利好公告的回报(Schwert酒店如穆勒和Schlingemann 2005,2000年,1990年,Loderer和马丁阿斯奎斯等,1983)(2006年)马尔季诺娃Renneboog的。但是,投标人股东实现异常立即返回各地公布之日,这是不显着异于零,无论正负。
同样,格尔根Renneboog的(2004年)结束,从兼并和收购是为股东创造价值为目标的股东赚大的正的异常报酬与平均投标人的股东不失去现有的全面的文献。同样,哈尔彭(1973),(1974)Mandelker阿斯奎斯(1983),德赛布拉德利和Kim(1​​988)证明,成功的收购为股东创造价值,但马拉泰斯塔(1983)和Roll(1986)反驳。虽然一些研究的结论是从收购的收益目标(阿斯奎斯多德(1980)Mandelker(1974),(1983)哈尔彭(1973)),一些人发现,收益洒收购方与目标之间(布罗伊勒斯弗兰克斯对比双方和其他证明报告收益和赫克特(1977年),投标公司股东赚取积极和显着的收益,成功收购(阿斯奎斯(1983),布鲁纳和穆林斯(1983),多德和低价注入上市公司等等,而通过重组本地(1977)),(弗兰克和Harris,1989)。
大量的研究已经做了显著的原因下,这种变化的目标和投标人的股东回报。这些研究已经暴露的一些目标和投标人的股东回报价值驱动。在下面的章节中,我们提出了在现有发现几个这些价值驱动程序。
2.2.1投标表格 - 敌对与友好的投标
定义为敌意,如果收购的潜在目标管理,以任何理由,拒绝收购要约。除其他原因,敌意可能是由于提取更高的溢价收购方对目标公司股东(Schwert酒店,2000)或目标管理可能会认为该建议并不符合他们公司的策略(格尔根Renneboog的,2006年)。此外,根据股东福利假说黄和步行(1987)所指出的时有阻力出价,它可能会导致股东权益的形式从目前的投标人或另一个更高的溢价。一致的股东福利假说,库默尔和霍夫曼斯特的(1978)占较高的超额回报在最初公布一个月的敌意收购报价。
敌意收购而产生较高的超额回报为目标(第0天的12.6%和近30%的价格运行)上公布当天投标人股东赚取-2.5%的研究显示,他们反对收购Georgen Renneboog的(2004年)。另外,如果出价是一个友好的一个,或者是合并,那么他们表明,收购产生的2.5%的正回报。如投标人反应的原因,他们说是因为当敌意收购的目标,股价会自动反映这种反对的期望,从而导致报价上调,因此应支付的收购溢价。此外,投标人通常会产生额外的费用,包括诉讼和延迟,并可能被迫支付更高的保费目标方股东鼓励招标(Jarrel和波尔森,1986)。另一方面,格雷戈里(1997); Loughran和Vijh的(1997)和郎等(1989)显示,敌意收购产生更高的目标,以及投标人的回报,而不是友好的兼并或收购的公告。从合并后的公司的角度来看,Kuipers的人(2003年)显示,提供目标公司的管理层的反对,值创造了合并后的公司,但目标公司股东赚取回报率较低(尽管不显着的水平)。
过多的管理性,另一方面,可能只会阻碍交易成功的黄和步行(1987)指出。同样,Jensen和低价注入上市公司等等,而通过重组本地(1983)显示,由于反对的出价投标公司的收购成本增加,他们可能会放弃收购企图,否则(如果出价很友好,或抵抗力较差)已经盈利。放弃这些尝试生产Jensen和低价注入上市公司等等,而通过重组本地长期的截断现象。
赞成目前的管理人员,如果目标公司股东拒绝出价,那么股东不成功的投标公司将不会遇到任何不正常的价格变动。然而,如果同一目标公司接受另一竞购对手的报价,然后的主要招标公司将经历显着的财富损失围绕日内要约收购成功竞购对手(布拉德利等人,1982)。
寻找在企业管治方面视图,罗西和Volpin的(2004)的敌意收购表明,敌对的交易更有可能发生在更好地保护股东的国家,因为良好的保护少数股东权益,使控制更加争论的减少私人利益控制。
2.2.2支付现金与股票的方法
一些实证研究提供一些收购的现金和股票收购的理由。累积异常报酬率,投标者和目标,往往不同,最显着和明显的形式发放。黄和Servaes的散步(1987),Travlos(1987),(1991)和安德拉德等人(2001)发现,现金收购诱导显着较高的超额回报比股票报价,目标和招标公司股东,在其他也就是说,付款方式影响,必须支付的收购溢价。
由格尔根Renneboog的(2004年)的目标是高度敏感,使用的支付手​​段,发现了强有力的证据。他们表明现金提供诱导车相比增加了10%的汽车,同比增长只有6.7%的股权报价。总之,它们表明,不管任何事件窗口,CAAR现金出资的出价明显高于其他投标。
相反,格尔根Renneboog的(2004)收购公司汽车表现出完全不同的景象。不管事件窗口的大小,投标公司的股东更有利的反应比现金优惠(0.4%)股票报价(1%)。这一结果是在矛盾的Travlos(1987)显示,为纯股票报价,投标人股东遇到重大损失,而现金提供投标公司股东获得正常的回报率。其中包括混合的实证研究结果已报告由黄和步行(1987),弗兰克斯和哈里斯,哈里斯和雷文斯克罗夫特(1991),(1989)埃克博等人(1990)和Loughran和Vijh的(1997)。
这种反应可以解释为赞成的现金收购要约,以股票报价投标人的能力的信心的信号不共享未来的价值创造与目标的股东(格尔根Renneboog的,2004)利用从潜在收购的协同效应。此外,(1990年)Amihud,列弗,Travlos的的,建立对Harris和Raviv(1988)和Stulz(1988)发​​现,值控制的经理谁愿意支付现金用于收购,以避免股权稀释和可能遭受的损失控制(戈什鲁兰,1998)。
其中包括,有几个因素会影响付款的选择。首先,在收购目标时,以现金补偿,交易成为纳税的,投标人最终支付更高的溢价来的目标。另一方面,如果他们的股票补偿(或任何其他形式的支付),税务责任,可以推迟或立即支付,视情况而定,投标人不必支付更高的溢价(黄走,1987)。因此,由于这些差别的税务处理现金优惠有更高的回报比股票报价,也就是说,目标要求更高的溢价的情况下,这将迫使他们立即支付其资本收益税。 (Wansley巷,杨[42])(1987年Travlos)
此外,机构的影响(正如由简森(1986)),也可以使用现金而不是股票的收购方,作为收购货币的动机。公司将倾向于使用多余的现金流,以资助其他活动,如收购,而不是向股东返回此金额。因此谁是受机构的影响,公司将用现金融资收购其他方法相比,。
调控作用的另一个因素是影响付款的选择。 Wansley巷和杨(1983)注意,股票报价,收购人必须事先采取从美国证券交易委员会批准的目标开始之前投标他们的股票。黄和散步(1987)认为,这可能会成为一个问题,在敌意收购的批准的处理时间很长,余地信息泄漏到首选收购目标管理,或者它可能诱发其他投标人参加比赛。相反,如果投标人使用现金而不是股票,他们可以开始采集目标几周内,并避免不必要的支付高昂的保费,由于竞争性投标。因此,如果使用现金,那么美国证券交易委员会的事先批准,是不必要的和收购变得更快,使其在敌意收购的情况下,时间是至关重要的支付和交易的速度此事的首选形式。
在完全与对称知情剂市场,支付方式为融资收购是经济无关。但是,如果收购公司的管理者都知道,他们的股份价值超过目前的市场价格,也就是,他们价格过高,那么他们会更喜欢用现金收购​​融资。相反,如果他们觉得他们的股份低于市场价格(被低估),那么他们将要使用股票作为收购货币。管理者的这种行为的产生是由于信息不对称(迈尔斯和Mjluf的,1934年),另一个因素是影响支付方式。当招标公司,采用权益融资出价,市场将认为这是负面新闻,对投标人的真正的股票价值(信令假说)。公布当天的市场参与者的这种负面反应,反映投标人股东的负收益。因此,这样一个公司的管理者和外部投资者之间的信息不对称,可能有付款的选择要使用的轴承。
(2004格尔根Renneboog的)表明,在他们的样本的收购,较小的所有现金出价,而较大的涉及股权。这意味着大型竞标,选择的付款方式是所有的股票或混合要约,因为它变得难以筹集如此大量的现金。因此,选择不作为支付手段的一个信号,市场对投标人的权益上/低估。
总之,有必要控制付款方法最跨境交易是现金收购建议(斯塔克斯和伟,2003;罗西和Volpin的,2004年),我们需要控制的可能性较高的超额收益目标和投标驱动的事实,这些收购都是现金收购要约。
2.2.3相对尺寸
从的目标大小来看,增加它的大小相对于收购方将造成影响,这将是很容易观察到收购方返回。在这种情况下,如果收购是一个增加一个人的财富,最大的正回报将反映当目标相比是比较大的招标公司。阿斯奎斯,布鲁纳和穆林斯(1983)和Travlos(1987年)的相对大小和收购方的回报之间的关系上进行他们的测试,他们发现了一个显着的正相关关系,两者之间的(贾雷尔和Poulson芯片,1989)。然而,格尔根Renneboog的(2008)认为在他们的研究中,相对于投标人大小的目标的大小没有一个目标和投标人的财富效应的影响。但他们也强调,这样的结论可能的原因可能是因为他们的研究主要集中在大型并购,并因此平均相对大小相当均匀。贾雷尔和波尔森(1989)的结论为目标的大小,相对于投标人的增加,投标公司股东其股价经历了显着的升值。他们作为优秀的权益除以发行在外的股份的投标人在3个月前的交易的价值目标的价值测量的相对大小。
Ghosh和鲁兰(1998)研究控制权的经营者激励机制之间的相互关系,在合并后的公司的相对大小。他们的研究结果说明,如果目标公司是比较小的收购,那么合并后的公司在目标公司的经理的影响也会很小。此外,他们收购的方法和目标的相对大小之间的关系,并得出结论,获取关心的潜在摊薄股权或失去控制权,同时获取目标相比,他们在规模较大的企业经理,会更愿意提供现金作为补偿,而不是权益。
在计算合并对投标人的影响,大尺寸的投标人的目标相比,可能会造成潜在的问题,弗兰克和哈里斯(1989)所提出的。他们认为,这种差异大小可以使来自收购的收益或亏损暧昧。反之,如果目标是大于投标人,投标人不显着丧失。控制投标人的大小,可以帮助我们检测收购的影响股价(弗兰克和哈里斯,1989)投标人。
2.2.4招标和目标公司的产业关联度 - 聚焦与多元化战略
多元化业务具有几个优点更大的经营效率,激励放弃净现值为正的项目,更大的债务融资能力,降低税收。相反,那里的相关费用等多元化,如无限制资源进行价值投资,减少交叉补贴,使贫困阶层漏性能更好的分部,并鼓励中央和部门经理之间错位的资源。有没有明确的预测的整体价值多元化的影响。
伯杰和地平线(1994)在他们的研究多元化对公司价值的影响是的多元化降低价值。他们估计各分部的价值,就好像它是作为一个单独的公司运作,并得出结论,丢失的平均值为13%至15%,在样本期间。多样化减少这方面的损失。评论和贾雷尔(1994)发现一个异常报酬和多样化之间的负相关关系。同样,郎和Stulz(1994)也找到了股东的财富和多元化之间的负相关关系。
DOUKAS等(2001)研究了企业多元化的影响,在短期和长期财富效应101瑞典投标事务所。结果都是一样的,多样化以上不创造价值。此外,他们提供的证据表明,非相关多元化导致更大的代理成本和经营效率低下,其中有一个短期和长期表现坚挺的负面影响。这意味着,非相关多元化是对股东财富的负担。相反,他们强调,如果企业从事他们的主要业务线相关多元化扩张,然后公布及收购后的性能提升来实现(DOUKAS等,2001)。同样,哈里斯和Ravenscraft的(1991)提出这种关系多样化,不仅增加公司的效率,但也有积极的作用的规模经济和市场力量。 (2006)马尔季诺娃Renneboog的发现,当投标公司从事相关多元化,竞价股东赚取显着,而目标公司股东赚取更多的无关diverfication的。这种相反的影响财富的原因是投标人往往过高由于积极性招标,这意味着收购以外股东的利润动机驱动。
2.2.5投标竞争本质 - 单与多投标
许多研究者(布拉德利,金德赛,1988; Kuipers的,2003)的实证分析证明只有更大的资产的投标竞争,更高的回报目标,并降低收购方的回报。弗兰克斯和哈里斯目标异常报酬高出三分之一或三分之二时,有多个投标。这些结果是在与布拉德利,德赛金(1988),多个投标人的状态,增加目标公司股东超过40%的异常报酬,较单离场的情况下低于30%。
然而,弗兰克和哈里斯(1987)做的原因,在挑战投标,总的协同收益较大。因此,目标公司股东不仅受益于招标公司股东的费用,而且还从交易的协同收益。这是承认Jarrel和波尔森(---)认为,收购,如果没有挑战,那么目标将不得不接受由投标人提供的股份数量,但在相反的情况下​​,由于竞争,将受益于合并收益的卖出价将被带动起来的回报将更大份额的目标相比,投标人的目标。弗兰克斯和哈里斯(1987)也进行了直接比较研究两国之间有争议的投标。他们的证据表明有争议的投标导致更高的目标在这两个国家的财富。
几乎所有的研究人员已经发现,目标财富的增加在有争议的投标,但在投标人的财富,是一个混合的发现。 ,虽然布拉德利,金正日和德赛(1988)表明,收购收购公司股东财富显着的正面单投标人竞赛中,不显着异于零多个投标人的情况下,弗兰克斯和哈里斯(1987)发现没有这样的丰硕成果。弗兰克斯和哈里斯解释说,投标人之间的竞争,降低了平均收益为收购方,特别严重的负面影响后期投标人的收购,俗称白骑士。
贾雷尔和布拉德利,此外,推测威廉姆斯法案“后,取得的回报应该进一步下降,现在竞争的投标人可以使用原投标人所产生的信息,目标回报率应有所增加。他们证明自己的假设,因为他们发现的异常报酬率下降,从平均约9%的投标人之前,“威廉姆斯法案”的6%左右,“威廉姆斯法案”通过后,目标增加了约20%(贾雷尔和回报波尔森,---)
2.3投标者在公司治理法规的差异和目标性能的影响和跨境收购价值
公司控制权的权利,以确定企业资源管理被定义为 - 也就是说,高层经理的薪酬雇用,解雇,并设置权[Fama和詹森(1983年a,B)]。它包括的活动范围控制使用企业资源,如法律和监管制度,并在产品和投入市场的竞争,一个公司的董事会的管理控制多数议席。当招标公司收购目标公司,目标公司的管理和控制活动转移到收购公司的董事董事会。因此,通过收购收购公司的高层管理人员获得的权利管理目标公司的资源。
合同设备,如跨境兼并和收购,(重新)注册成立,交叉上市,是手段,使企业改变其国家的企业管治标准,并采用一个新的(格尔根Renneboog的,2004年)。据罗西和Volpin(2004)出售给一家外国公司是一个形式类似合同收敛到更好的公司治理和资本市场比较发达的国家上市的决定。 Pagano的,等。 (2002)和里斯和魏斯巴赫的(2002)强调该公司的少数股东名单国外法律保护薄弱的国家,来自其他国家的企业相比,更频繁。
然而,一个世界性的企业管治标准衔接的可能性是各种院士之间的辩论的一个主题。虽然汉斯曼和卡拉克曼的(2001)建议,正式收购方治标准趋同将很快发生,咖啡(1999)认为,在公司治理diffences会坚持,但也有一些程度的功能收敛(罗西和Volpin的,2004年)。
罗西和Volpin(2004)专注于并购活动和聚集各国的目标保费。他们推测,资本成本降低,当收购方冰雹比目标从优秀的公司治理体系,使收购目标的一个明智的选择。在同样的思路,咖啡(1999)的结论是,从更好的投资者保护制度的企业将获得企业从低保障系统。此外,当大多数目标是从股东权益保护较弱及披露惯例的国家,他们的立场,以获得较低的资金成本高的投资者保护相关。的罗西和Volpin(2004)基地La Porta等人(2000),他们的研究结果显示,市场更为活跃,兼并和收购是一个更强大的企业管治制度的结果。他们的结论是跨境并购的增强趋同较强的投资者保护,其中有一个积极的影响量的收购,出价保费和敌意收购的数量。此外,更好地保护投标人的国家,允许所有股票报价的投标人。
最近的研究已经进行了一个公司的估值上的法律和公司治理环境的影响进行评估。这些研究已经完成,同时在公司特定和产业化水平。 (2005年)BRIS Cabolis的Kuipers在等人(2003)是其中几个人的公司特定环境,他们的研究重点。
Kuipers在等人(2003)测试美国的目标,外国收购和合并后的公司的股东回报上的法律环境的影响。他们进一步测试收购公司承包代理成本假说所反映的LLSV指数基础上的证券持有人提供保护的法律环境和质量。的承包代理成本假说认为,公司从投资者保护较强的国家将按照其股东的利益(或债权人,如果债权人的保护是优于股东),将相应进行增加(或数值减少)投资价值。另外,有合约收敛假说,其中指出,从投资者保护较弱的国家的企业获得高投资者保护公司,其目的是引导自己一个更好的系统治理。支持Wurgler(2000年)和LLSV(2002)Kuipers在等人(2003)的结论是强规则的存在,法律和安全所有者保护机制作为替代承包机制,减轻经典公司的代理成本(Kuiper等人,2003)。